top of page
Search

Projects, Procurement and Market Power in Construction Contracting

Topics

  • Market power, auctions and procurement

  • Contractors as price takers

  • Clients as price takers

  • Subcontractors as price takers

  • Project complexity and contracts

  • Market power and projects


Definitions

  • The definition of a market is: an arrangement where the interaction of demand from buyers and supply from sellers determines the price and quantity of goods and services exchanged.

  • The definition of market power is: the ability of a buyer or seller to manipulate prices through control over its demand or supply. The extreme cases are monopoly or monopsony, but a firm can gain market power by controlling a large portion of the market or as a member of an oligopoly.

  • Market participants with market power are price makers, while those without are price takers.


Questions

  • A wide range of views are held on questions such as the types of markets in the industry, the competitive behavior and role of firms, the relationships between firms and the products and services they provide within those markets. There is, however, universal agreement that building and construction is an industry of projects, made up of a interlinked series of markets for projects of many different types.

  • Procurement from an economic perspective follows Laffontand Tirole’sA Theory of Incentives in Procurement and Regulation(1993), where the supplier has knowledge about costs the buyer does not, and thus has to find ways to infer the supplier’s costs, typically through competitive bidding or offering prizes.

  • This discussion asks where and in what circumstances are participants in construction procurement and contracting price makers and price takers?


Rules of the Game

  • All buying and selling in contracting can be seen as a series of games in which buyers and sellers seek to optimise their returns.

  • Distinction made between one-off and repeated games.

  • Strategic behaviour in procurement uses market power, information asymmetry and bargaining to gain leverage.

  • Hidden information and hidden actions mean moral hazard and adverse selection are always possible.

  • What may be appropriate for a buyer on one construction project may not be appropriate on another.

  • Projects can be standardised, complicated or complex.

  • Frequency, scale and scope change from project to project.


Projects as Markets

  • Can an individual project be a temporary market in its own right?

  • The market for a single project is created by a client as they go through the procurement process, regardless of the particular system or method of procurement followed.

  • The client is the buyer of a bundle of goods and services from the contractor/s bidding or negotiating for the project, and their interaction on the scope (quantity) and price of the project is resolved when the agreement or contract is exchanged.

  • Does the client have buyer power?


The Project Market



Monopsony

  • A market with single buyer is a monopsony (the opposite of a monopoly).

  • The treatment of buyer power in economics is concerned with how firms can affect the terms of trade with their suppliers. A buyer has monopsony power if they can reduce the price paid below competitive levels (marginal cost) by withholding demand.

  • There is an important distinction between monopsony power and bargaining power, or the bargaining strength that a buyer has with respect to suppliers. The lower price obtained from monopsony power is achieved by actually purchasing less, but with bargaining power it can be achieved by the threat of purchasing less.


Bargaining Power

  • The supplier has hidden information about costs the client does not, but the client needs a way to find out supplier costs, typically done by competitive bidding or offering prizes.

  • The two other key factors that influence bilateral bargaining are:

1. The role of information and how extensive the information asymmetries

between the different parties, particularly hidden information. An informational

advantage is an advantage in terms of bargaining power.


2. Coordination (tacit or explicit) among suppliers, because the

presence/absence of incentives for suppliers to collude may

increase/decrease buyer bargaining power.



Contractors as Price Takers


Auctions

  • In a first-price procurement auction, the low bidder is awarded the contract.

  • In a common-values auction, the cost of performing the contract is common to all bidders but is uncertain, bids are based on estimates, and this sort of auction is said to give rise to the “winner’s curse”.

Bidding estimated cost can result in a loss because

the lowest of several independent estimates of the

actual cost, on average, is less than the actual cost.


Rational bidders avoid the winner’s curse by bidding

above their cost estimates.

  • The problem with first-price sealed bid auctions is that increasing the bid too little results in lost revenue to the contractor, while too much loses the competition. Vickrey proposed using a second-price sealed bid auction where the lowest bidder is awarded the contract at the second lowest price.

Procurement

  • First-price sealed bid auctions are widely used for building and construction projects, and are the basis of procurement systems that use competitive tendering.

  • However such sealed-bid auctions can be affected by uncertainty, cognitive bias like over-optimistic assumptions, technical errors in estimating and scheduling, and subject to information asymmetries between clients and contractors.

  • Bids typically cover a range and, if normally distributed, there will be a winning bid below the average of all bids. That average or median estimate of project costs has the highest probability of being the actual cost, and can be taken as the market price.

Client Surplus

  • The auction price Pa is below the equilibrium price P* due to cognitive biases and errors.

1. It augments the clients’ surplus

(C) by the same amount that it

reduces the contractors’ surplus.


2. There is a decrease in both

surpluses (A+B), a deadweight

loss.

  • This deadweight loss is a reduction in social welfare.


Brockmann concludes clients have market power, and the industry’s response to their use

of that power is to collude in a variety of ways.

  • He also, uniquely, argues for regulation of buyer power.

Widespread evidence of collusion in the construction industry would suggest this, in some circumstances, can be the case:

  • The Japanese dangosystem of market sharing on public works;

  • The Dutch industry cartel (650 companies fined €239 by NMain 2003);

  • The lift and elevator cartel (EU Competition Commission €992 fine in 2007);

  • Montreal’s ‘Fabulous 14’ control almost 80% of public work;

  • The Scandinavian ‘Big 3’ do around 70% of all building and construction;

  • Steel, cement and concrete industries are repeat offenders in many countries;

  • Australian fire installers, unsuccessful tender fees and housing contractors.

Office of Fair Trading

  • The number of cases between competition regulators and construction contractors and suppliers, and their industry associations, implies a structural problem in the industry, not just the actions of a few ‘bad apples’.

  • Charges brought against 112 firms by the OFT in 2008 were the culmination of a four-year effort. Began in 2007 as an investigation of the roofing industry in the Midlands, and quickly spread.

  • Ultimately, the OFT raided 57 businesses and received 37 leniency applications, but the underlying problem was larger than those figures suggest.

  • The OFT eventually had to cut off the investigation because it was uncovering more cartel behaviour than the agency could process, given its resources.

OECD Roundtable 2008

“Because of the very large number of small firms, the entire industry is often characterized as unconcentrated. That description is too broad, however, because not all construction companies do overlapping work and some segments are much less fragmented than others. For example, a limited number of general contractors are capable of managing the very large projects, whereas there are a great many small subcontractors. Competition among large general contractors and among specialty firms seems to be oligopolistic, while rivalry among small contractors who do basic labour tends to be closer to perfect competition.”
“… when relevant markets are defined, as opposed to considering the whole industry, competition is often limited because many firms are specialized or cannot compete on large projects … limited competition and substantial entry barriers can facilitate many different types of anticompetitive conduct, including unilateral and horizontal varieties. In addition, procurement procedures for construction projects are often conducive to collusion.”

OECD, Competition in the Construction Industry, pg. 9.


Two Views on Procurement

  • This might be called the regulator’s view, a quasi-legal series of repeated games between monopsonistclients and oligopolistic contractors within a defective institutional framework (that has nevertheless been in use for millennia).

  • Two responses from industry are the cost uncertainty and ruinous competition arguments:

Ruinous competition, or cut-throat competition, describes a situation where

competition results in prices that do not cover costs of production, particularly

fixed costs.

  • While there are some elements of truth in this, these are over-simplified views of how the industry often, but not always, works in practice:

Do clients really believe they have market power?

Do contractors actually run businesses that cannot be profitable?


Fundamental Transformation


  • For a buyer to have substantial market power they must be able to switch to an alternative supplier, or self supply, without incurring substantial sunk costs.

  • Once a contract is signed the client loses that power, which is Williamson’s Fundamental Transformation in TCE. Contractors do not have to collude to have market power, particularly if the contract allows payment for cost increases during construction.

  • However, prior to signing clients can potentially exercise market power through their choice of procurement method and type of contract. Those, in turn, are affected by the type and characteristics of each project.



Client as Price Taker


Cox 2009

Reactive – short term, arm’s length, transactional.

Proactive – collaborative with dedicated investment.


First tier - one supplier only, no buyer involvement.

Supply chain - the buyer selects from suppliers in as many tiers as possible, on basis of value.


“In construction supplier selection (one tier, short term) would cover the majority of cases, and supplier development (one tier, collaborative) most of the rest.”

Cox, A. Strategic Management of Construction Procurement,in O'Brien, W.J. et al. (eds) 2009. Construction Supply Chain Management Handbook.


Bargaining Power

  • The issue here, of a project as a market with the client as a single buyer, is the relative bargaining power on the buyer and seller sides.

  • The construction client can be in a weak bargaining position because there is no market price available as a reference point when negotiating with potential suppliers. Thus procurement is an information discovery process, with the client getting bidders to reveal prices.

  • Inderstand Mazzarotto suggest a definition of buyer power as the bargaining strength that a buyer has with respect to suppliers with whom it trades, where bargaining strength depends on the ability to credibly threaten to impose an opportunity cost if it is not granted a concession.

Inderstand Mazzarotto (2008) ‘Buyer power in distribution’, in Collins, W.D. (Ed.), Issues in Competition Law and Policy, 3. Chicago: ABA Section of Antitrust Law, 1953-1978.


Incentives

  • Construction contracts are also a bilateral incentive problem, with opportunities for information exchange and strategic interaction. Contracting becomes worthwhile when there is a temporal element to exchange, but using contracts for exchanges that depend on future events requires a commitment mechanism.

The 2016 Nobel to Hart and Holmstromwas for incomplete contracts and

incentives respectively.

  • For clients, construction procurement and contracts involve issues of:

1. Moral hazard and hidden action.

2. Adverse selection and hidden information.

3. Incompleteness and property rights.

  • In each case the client has limited or no access to relevant information. The less experienced the client the less informed they are likely to be.

Contractual Incompleteness

  • Hart argued the level of specification of a project is the determining factor in the type of contract that should be used. Based on his work in developing incentive theory and incomplete contract theory.

Hart (1995) Firms, Contracts, and Financial Structure, and Grossman and Hart

(1986) ‘The costs and benefits of ownership: A theory of vertical and lateral

integration’, Journal of Political Economy.

“Should the buyer of a customized good use competitive bidding or negotiation to select a contractor? … Auctions may perform poorly when projects are complex, contractual design is incomplete and there are few available bidders. Furthermore, auctions may stifle communication between buyers and sellers, preventing the buyer from utilizing the contractor’s expertise when designing the project.”

Bajari, P., McMillan, J. and Tadelis, S. (2008) ‘Auctions versus negotiations in procurement: an empirical analysis’, Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization.


Bajariand Tadelis

  • They consider (in Handbook of Procurement, 2006) the procurer’s decisions on how much to invest in design costs at the outset, because a more detailed and accurate design reduces the need to renegotiate changes, and the choice of a fixed-price or cost-plus payment structure. Their conclusions are:

1. For simple well specified projects, where contractual incompleteness is

negligible and performance is easy to verify, favour fixed-price contracts

awarded by competitive tender;

2. For complex and incompletely specified projects favour a cost-plus contract

awarded using negotiation with a reputable supplier;

3. For moderately complex projects that can be specified at moderate costs favour

a more complete design, selective tender and fixed-price contract. If potential

suppliers are scarce then save on design costs with a cost-plus contract.


Bajari, P. and Tadelis, S. (2006). ‘Incentives and award procedures: Competitive tendering versus negotiations in procurement’ in Dimitri, N., Piga, G. and Spagnolo, G. (Eds) Handbook of Procurement.


The Ratchet Effect

  • Laffontand Tirole (1986, 1988) analysed short-run contracting under information asymmetry, where the regulator (client) is unable to write any long-run contract with the regulated firm (contractor), but instead has to govern the relationship by a series of short-run, one-period contracts

  • This gives rise to the ratchet effect: If an agent works hard and shows a good result, the principal may demand even better results in the future therefore, anticipating this, the agent has little incentive to work hard in the first place.

  • The firm will also be reluctant to reveal that its costs are low, fearing that its information rents will be expropriated.

Laffontand Tirole(1986) ‘Using cost observation to regulate firms’, Journal of Political Economy and (1988) ‘The dynamics of incentive contracts’, Econometrica.



Subcontractors as Price Takers


A Multiplicity of Market Types

The fragmented nature of construction activity means that, on a construction project, there can be a range of market structures, with various different forms of relationships, interaction and contracts between them.


Concealment

  • McAfee and McMillan found that, in a first-price sealed-bid auction with independent private values, the expected revenue to the seller is greater if the number of bidders is concealed.

  • Thus risk-seeking subcontractors will be more likely to win the work, and at lower margins, if contractors do not reveal the number of subcontract bids they receive.

  • This is a useful insight into bidding and competitive behavior by both contractors and subcontractors. Contractors can exercise market power through the process of subcontracting, and the outcome will be the same as if they had exercised bargaining power with their suppliers.

McAfee, P.R. and McMillan, J. 1987. ‘Auction and bidding’, J. of Economic Literature.


Supply Chain Relationships

  • A contractor negotiating with potential subcontractors does have knowledge of their current prices, and often, but not always, has access to alternative suppliers and subcontractors. Therefore the contractor potentially has bargaining power.

  • If the subcontractors are hired at marginal cost then allocative efficiency will be maximized, but if the contractor has used their position to increase profits at the expense of subcontractors this will no longer be the case.

Another situation where an auction can lead to the winning bidder’s award price

being below the equilibrium price, in a perfectly competitive market.

  • However, some suppliers are also large firms in oligopolies, or a long-term contract can be more relational. Across the project sub-markets for labour, materials and components there is a range of market structures and product differentiation.

Management Style


Rahim’s five conflict management styles can be applied to supply chain and subcontractor relationships and contracts. Different suppliers will have degrees of market power, and different relationships with the contractor.

Rahim, M.A. 1983. A measure of styles of handling interpersonal conflict, Academy of Management Journal.